Red Ink Page 10
Bob Reischauer, seventy, is with the consensus. The physically towering economist, son of prominent Japan scholar Edwin Reischauer, is one of the wise men of budgeting in Washington. Recently retired as head of the Urban Institute think tank, he spent his entire career at CBO—he was one of Alice Rivlin’s lieutenants in the agency’s infancy—and at Democratic-leaning think tanks in Washington. Reischauer’s influence is amplified by his unusual combination of hard-nosed political realism with trenchant economic insight and by reporters’ affection for his pithy sound bites. “I’m a believer that Obama saved us from a world depression,” he said. “And the American people give him zero credit for that—99 percent of the population has no appreciation for what kind of threat it was.” That’s an overstatement: the public has warmed to the stimulus as time has passed and the economy has perked up. In a February 2012 Pew poll, 61 percent said it was “mostly good” for the economy, substantially more than the 38 percent who voiced approval two years earlier.
Whatever the merits, that money has been borrowed, and it has been spent—which leads to the second fact:
To rescue the economy, Obama piled more government debt on top of the debt that he inherited. He has yet to sell the public or Congress on a credible plan to avoid unsustainable increases in debt in the future.
On the day Obama took the oath of office, January 20, 2009, the U.S. government owed $6.3 trillion to others—$6,307,310,739,681.66 to be precise, according to the Treasury’s “Debt to the Penny” website. That works out to $54,000 per household or 45 percent of GDP, the yardstick that measures the debt against the size of the whole U.S. economy.
On February 13, 2012, when Obama sent his budget to Congress, the government owed $10.6 trillion—$10,596,768,009,341.49. That’s $90,000 per household, or nearly 70 percent of GDP, higher than at any time in the past sixty years.
The real problem lies ahead, as Reischauer suggested with his car-at-the-cliff analogy. Obama said as much the day his February 2012 budget was released: “[T]ruth is we’re going to have to make some tough choices in order to put this country back on a more sustainable fiscal path. By reducing our deficit in the long term, what that allows us to do is to invest in the things that will help grow our economy right now. We can’t cut back on those things that are important for us to grow. We can’t just cut our way into growth. We can cut back on the things that we don’t need, but we also have to make sure that everyone is paying their fair share for the things that we do need.”
But Obama’s latest budget showed that even if Congress accepted every one of his money-saving and tax-increasing proposals and even if his health care law worked as hoped and even if the economy steadily improved, the government would still need to borrow another $4 trillion over the next four years, and the ratio of debt to GDP would keep climbing. And that doesn’t count trillions more in unfunded promises to pay benefits in the future, which are not formally recorded on the government’s books.
ABOUT THE NATIONAL DEBT
For most of recent American history, most U.S. government borrowing was domestic—the Liberty Bonds sold during World War I, War Bonds sold during World War II, the savings bonds that generations of grandparents gave at graduation time, the U.S. Treasury bonds held in Americans’ trust accounts and pension funds. “We owe it to ourselves” was the comforting mantra. No longer. Back in 1955, when the federal debt was much smaller, less than 5 percent was held by foreigners. Foreign holdings began to climb in 1970 and surged in the 2000s. Today, foreign governments and private investors hold nearly half of all the U.S. government debt outstanding. A big chunk of this lending is from China and Japan. They have been big savers, so they have a lot of money to lend to foreigners. And they export a lot more to the United States (when dollars flow into China) than they import (when dollars flow out of China), which leaves them with a growing stockpile of dollars that has to be invested somewhere. The U.S. Treasury bond is still the safest place to put them.
Right now, all this federal government borrowing isn’t a problem. While Washington has borrowed heavily over the past few years, consumer and business borrowing has been subdued. Measured as a percentage of GDP, borrowing by the U.S. economy as a whole—not only the federal government but also state and local governments, businesses, and households—peaked in early 2009 and has been falling since. As Massachusetts Institute of Technology economist Simon Johnson and his co-blogger James Kwak put it in their new book, White House Burning: “If the Treasury Department never had to pay interest (and could always borrow as it needed), the national debt would not matter very much.”
But the federal government does have to pay interest. Even though the U.S. Treasury borrows more cheaply than almost anyone else on the planet, the U.S. government paid $230 billion in net interest last year, more than triple the $64 billion it spent on all nondefense research and development, from medical research to space exploration. And that’s with interest rates at extraordinarily low levels. When rates return to normal, perhaps around 5 percent, each additional $1 trillion in debt will add $50 billion a year to the government’s annual interest payments.
And even the mighty U.S. government cannot assume it will always be able to borrow whatever it needs cheaply. The fact that the Chinese, in particular, hold so much of the federal debt—about 25 percent according to the U.S. Treasury’s estimates—conjures up a lot of angst, and that doesn’t count the Chinese holdings of debt of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, the mortgage lenders backed by the U.S. government. The worry is either that the Chinese will yank all their money out at once (not likely, given that doing so would tank the U.S. economy and with it their investments and exports) or that the reserves give the Chinese leverage over U.S. economic and foreign policies. (They do.) But even if the United States were borrowing from reliable allies, the more borrowed from abroad, the bigger the share of future Americans’ income that goes overseas to pay interest and principal.
For all the rhetoric from politicians of both parties about the dangers of debt and deficits, in the end, little was actually done about it in 2011 or 2012. “Kicking the can down the road” became an almost daily mantra in the press, and an accurate one.
One piece of recent legislation took direct aim at the deficit: the Budget Control Act. The law was passed in August 2011 in order to persuade reluctant members of Congress to take the politically unpopular step of voting to raise the ceiling on the federal debt, a bizarre practice in which Congress votes once to spend money and then votes again later to pay the credit card bill when it arrives. Essentially trying to tie its own hands—as it did from 1990 to 2002—Congress set hard ceilings for each of the next ten years on the 40 percent of spending that it appropriates annually, the panoply of domestic and defense items from aircraft carriers to the National Dam Safety Program described in chapter 3 but not Social Security or Medicare or other benefit programs. The caps allow this spending to rise about 2 percent a year, not enough to keep up with expected inflation, which in the world of budgeting is considered a cut of $1 trillion over ten years. If, and it’s a big if, the caps hold, spending on everything outside of Social Security, major health programs, and interest would come in below 8 percent of GDP in 2022, lower than at any time in the past forty years.
Congress then took one more step. It pointed a gun at itself (or, if you listen to Panetta, at the Pentagon budget) by mandating further across-the-board defense and domestic spending cuts beginning in January 2013—unless Congress and the president agree on an alternative way to bring projected deficits down by an additional $1.2 trillion over the next ten years. This self-imposed deadline could prompt a significant attack on the deficit some time after the November 2012 elections. Or Congress and the president could undo it, kicking the can down the road again.
WHERE ARE WE NOW?
Each January, the Congressional Budget Office attempts to show where the fiscal ship is headed before Congress tries to steer it with changes to taxes and spending. One telling measure of how conte
ntious budget politics have become is the increasing difficulty of getting agreement even on this starting point, known in Washington as “the baseline.” (When there’s talk in the newspapers of a $500 billion, ten-year deficit-reduction package, that means some combination of taxes and spending is projected to reduce future deficits by $500 billion from some baseline.)
Crafting baselines has never been easy: they rest on forecasts of everything from the stock market to the number of elderly hips that will be replaced, and those forecasts are certain to be wrong. Understanding baselines hasn’t been easy either: if it takes a 4 percent increase in Medicare spending to provide the same services next year as this year, then baseline accounting says that a 3 percent increase in Medicare spending is a 1 percent cut. And if that isn’t enough to give you a headache, the baseline-making task has grown tougher lately because Congress and presidents have stamped expiration dates on many costly tax and spending programs, and then repeatedly extended them. So should the baseline assume that Medicare spending will go down because the law says doctors’ fees will be slashed? Or should it assume that Congress will, as it has to date, waive the fee cuts? Ultimately, what matters is where Congress and the president end up, not where they start. But defining the starting point and crafting the baseline are important to the politics and public perceptions of the budget—they’re used by one side to magnify the size of the spending cuts or tax changes proposed by the other side—and politics and perceptions have a lot to do with what actually happens.
Pretending that Congress will let taxes rise and spending fall sharply at the start of 2013 can provide a dangerously misleading picture of the course on which the federal government is set. So the CBO has crafted an alternative. It projects future spending, taxes, and deficits if Congress extends all the Bush tax cuts for everyone at year-end, continues to adjust the pesky alternative minimum tax so it doesn’t reach ever deeper into the middle class, and continues to waive the provision in a 1997 deficit-reduction law that would cut Medicare doctor fees. Not everyone likes this approach, but it’s a useful road map to where the budget is heading without a course correction.
What does it show? “The good news is that the improving economy will reduce the deficit as a share of GDP considerably over the next few years,” said Doug Elmendorf, the current CBO director. As more people get jobs, more tax receipts will flow into the Treasury and spending on unemployment compensation and the like will come down. “The bad news,” he continued, “is that the improvement will still leave the deficit so large that, if we maintain our current spending and tax policies, debt will continue to rise sharply, relative to GDP.”
In this steady-as-she-goes scenario, spending driven by the aging of the population and rising health costs climbs faster than revenues. A lot faster. Deficits of $1 trillion or more would be the norm, and the national debt would approach 100 percent of GDP within a decade—and climb still higher in the years after that.
No one really knows how much the U.S. government can borrow before global investors get uneasy and begin to demand higher interest rates. The national debt exceeded 100 percent of GDP during World War II and then came down as the economy sprinted. But history suggests that debt of that level is in the danger zone. Think Argentina, circa 2001. Think Greece, circa 2012.
“If a country has not balanced its long-run budget when the long run arrives, then the market balances its budget for it—and does so in a way that nobody in the country likes,” Brad DeLong, a Berkeley economist and blogger, and a former Clinton adviser, has written. Then he added, drily, “[T]he long run seems to vary between three years and 200 years, depending.”
The 2012 election campaign has produced a lot of talk about taxes, spending, and deficits, much of it less than useful in understanding the choices the country faces. Basically, there are three poles in the debate.
The first says: The deficit is a problem. But not now, especially when there is still so much unemployment. The poster boy: Paul Krugman, a Princeton University economist and New York Times columnist.
The second says: The deficit is a problem. And the solution is to shrink the government and cut taxes. The poster boy: Paul Ryan, the Republican congressman from Wisconsin and chairman of the House Budget Committee.
The third says: The deficit is a big problem. In fact, it is the “transcendent threat to our economic future.” The poster boy: Peter G. Peterson, an octogenarian who is spending a large part of his considerable fortune to warn about the five-alarm fiscal fire ahead.
IT’S UNEMPLOYMENT, STUPID
Paul Krugman is not and probably never will be a policy maker. But he is formidably armed with a Nobel Prize, a perch on the op-ed page of the New York Times, and a very sharp pen. Drawn to economics initially by a set of Isaac Asimov’s science-fiction novels in which social scientists save the world, Krugman earned his Ph.D. at MIT and won the American Economic Association’s prize for the most accomplished economist under forty. Krugman’s most noteworthy academic work focuses on international trade and economic geography. Outside the profession, he began to make his mark as a polemicist about twenty years ago and has been writing twice a week for the Times since 1999, while blogging in between columns.
Krugman’s world is black-and-white: There are good guys and bad guys, smart guys and dumb ones, truth tellers and liars—and most of the bad guys are Republicans. His columns, speeches, and books often offer more ammunition than argument, bolstering those who agree with him rather than changing the minds of those who don’t. But compared to other economists and to many policy makers, Krugman saw early how big a blow the economy had suffered. As a result, he advocated for far more fiscal and monetary stimulus than Obama eventually got Congress to approve and Fed chairman Ben Bernanke got his colleagues to pursue. Keynes was right, he shouted. Take his advice.
Rahm Emanuel, Obama’s first chief of staff, once dismissed Krugman as economically brilliant and politically naive. “How many bills has he passed?” he asked. To which Krugman replied, “The question is why Obama didn’t ask for what the economy needed, then bargain from there.”
Krugman’s attitude toward the deficit is fuggedaboutit. “Premature deficit reduction,” he has said, risks “diverting attention from the more immediately urgent task of reducing unemployment.” Shouldn’t we worry that the rest of the world won’t keep lending the U.S. government more money? No, Krugman said. The interest rates that the bond market is charging on long-term loans to the U.S. government suggest that investors aren’t worrying about that prospect, so why should the U.S. government? Europe, in his view, provided an instructive case study of misguided fiscal austerity. Countries like Greece that were forced to cut spending aggressively to reduce borrowing strangled their economies and choked off the very growth that would allow them to pay off future debts.
“If we had slashed spending to ward off the invisible bond vigilantes … we’d be emulating Europe, and hence emulating Europe’s failure,” he wrote. We were wise, and we’d be wiser still if we gave the economy another dose of stimulus, he argued.
IT’S SPENDING, STUPID
After Republicans took control of the House, Paul Ryan became chairman of the House Budget Committee, and the most prominent Republican voice on budget matters. His fiscal script, called “A Path to Prosperity,” outlined unprecedented changes to the federal budget. Social Security was left alone, but he proposed big changes in the health programs. Federal spending on Medicaid’s long-term care coverage would be capped and turned over to the states. Those who turn sixty-five after 2022 would be offered vouchers to buy something resembling today’s fee-for-service Medicare or private insurance; to save money, each voucher would be worth less than the CBO currently projects health insurance for the elderly will cost. The notion was that the constraints on spending—“reform,” Ryan called it—would force the health care system to get more efficient. Critics said they simply shifted the costs onto the beneficiaries. But that was just a start. Ryan also proposed shrinking th
e rest of the federal government. Spending on everything outside Social Security, the health insurance programs, and interest would go from 12 percent of GDP in 2010 to 6 percent by 2022, he said, though the outline didn’t specify what would be cut.
Unlike the deficit-über-alles crowd, Ryan said he wanted to cut taxes, too. Although he didn’t offer details—budget resolutions generally don’t—he called for lower tax rates for both households and corporations. Backed by economists at the conservative Heritage Foundation (and without the endorsement of the CBO), Ryan predicted a resulting surge in economic growth that would produce enough revenues to reduce future deficits and bring down the debt.
“You shouldn’t put yourself in a position of trying to feed ever-higher spending with higher revenues, because you’ll never catch up,” he argued. His framework rejected what he called the “shared scarcity mentality” of “ever-higher taxes and bureaucratically rationed health care.”
Krugman described Ryan’s plan as “a strange combination of cruelty and insanely wishful thinking.” House Republicans voted for it, but many were uneasy, believing that the far-reaching changes to Medicare (which were altered in the 2012 iteration of the Ryan plan) made them an easy mark for Democrats on the campaign trail.
But Ryan was looking beyond the next election: “I believe the way to make change is to shift the political center of gravity as best you can, by putting ideas out there, solutions out there, and surviving the gauntlet of demagoguery you’ll inevitably receive,” he said.